What Are We Getting for All That Obamacare Spending?

Having a lot of health insurance doesn’t mean having a lot of health care. GETTY

 


 

One reason the United States spends more on health care than other countries is that we are obsessive about health insurance instead of health care.

When the British National Health Service or the Canadian Medicare system spends additional money, they spend it employing doctors, building hospitals or buying medical equipment. When the U.S. government spends more money, we give it to insurance companies.

Take Obamacare. We are currently spending $214 billion a year insuring people through Medicaid (which is mostly contracted out to private insurers) and the Obamacare exchanges. At $1,731 for every household in America, that’s a great deal of money being transferred from taxpayers to insurance companies every year.

What are we getting for all that spending? Are people getting more health care? If they are, what difference is that making?

Apparently, few people find these questions interesting. In a Google search on “Obamacare,” every article I encountered discussed health insurance, but not health care. Even at the Obama Foundation website, the focus is entirely on insurance, not care.

Doctor Visits Have Fallen

Nonetheless, one scholarly study finds there has been no overall increase in health care in the US since the enactment of Obamacare. More on that below. The number of doctor visits per capita actually fell over the last decade. That’s surprising, because our population has been aging, and older people require more health care.

Unfortunately, there is nothing particularly new here. When Obamacare was enacted, it was expected to cost close to $1 trillion over the next ten years. But there was no serious discussion of what we were going to buy with all that spending – not in Congress, not in the mainstream media, or even in the health policy community.

Econ 101 teaches that all societies face a production possibility frontier. The typical textbook example is the choice between guns (military goods) and butter (consumer goods). In our case, it is health care versus other goods and services. To have more of one, you have to have less of the other.

To have more health care, we have to have more doctors, more nurses, more hospital beds, etc. Without any increase in supply, for one group of people to get more care, some other group has to get less.

We saw a vivid illustration of that during the Covid pandemic. In order to tend to the needs of a sudden surge in Covid patients, health care providers had to delay care for the non-Covid patients.

Throwing Money at the Problem

Our experience with Obamacare is similar to our experience with every major health program Congress has passed or even considered passing. We begin with a claim of unmet needs; we decide on a large sum of money to throw at the problem; but we never ask how the money can meet unmet needs if nothing is done on the supply side.

Medicare for the elderly and Medicaid for the poor were huge programs, even when they were started in 1965. In a short period of time the number of people who lacked health insurance dropped from nearly 25 percent to under 15 percent of the population.

As a result, physician visits by low-income people increased 6.2% and surgical procedures among the elderly increased 14.7%. But since there was no increase in the ability of the system to supply medical services, these increases were offset by a decrease in care delivered to the non-poor and the non-elderly. A study in the American Journal of Public Health found that “society-wide utilization of medical care remained unchanged.”

Even though there was an increase in health care services for seniors, MIT professor Amy Finkelstein discovered that the passage of Medicare had no effect on the health of the elderly—at least as measured by mortality. The additional spending set off a bout of health care inflation for all patients, however.

What lessons did Washington politicians learn as a result of this experience? Apparently, none at all.

During the first term of the Clinton Administration, Hillary Clinton proposed a plan to reform the private health care system and insure the remaining uninsured. But although that proposal consumed thousands of pages of analysis and discussion, almost no one asked what the nation would have less of in order to have more health care.

No Overall Increase in Health Care Utilization

Under Obamacare, the number of people without health insurance fell from 15.5 percent of the population in 2010 to 7.9 percent by 2022. Yet the study cited above found that health care utilization across all of society did not increase at all. There was some shifting, as low-income patients got more care, but that care was offset by reductions elsewhere in the system. In particular, “a 3.5-percentage-point increase in the proportion of persons earning less than or equal to 138% of the federal poverty level with at least 1 office visit was offset by small, nonsignificant reductions among the rest of the population.”

You might think that prescription drugs are different. If Congress liberalizes insurance for drugs, the drug companies can supply as much as patients demand. But even in the field of pharmaceuticals, there appears to be no limit to the ability of Congress to waste taxpayer money.

When Congress created Medicare Part D to pay for drugs in 2003, it created a $15.6 trillion unfunded liability for the federal government, looking indefinitely into the future. That was more than the unfunded liability in Social Security. Yet economist Andrew Rettenmaier discovered that only 7 percent of the benefits actually bought new drugs for seniors. The other 93 percent simply transferred to government (and therefore to taxpayers) the bill for drugs the elderly or their insurers were already buying. Only one in every thirteen dollars represented a new drug purchase.

Interestingly, the help given to the small number of people who were not otherwise getting medications actually reduced Medicare’s spending, as drugs were substituted for more expensive doctor and hospital therapies. But this profit on the truly needy was overwhelmed by the cost of giving the benefit to those who didn’t need it—a cost that has created an enormous obligation for current and future taxpayers.

See my latest post at Forbes.

 

 

 

1 Comment

  1. Brilliant article, but I wonder if part of the reason we haven’t seen an increase in health outcomes is due to the processed food revolution, which took off in the 1960s and continues to this day. Now, 73 percent of Americans are overweight or obese, which fuels both heart disease, cancer and diabetes, among other illnesses. At many restaurants, meals that would have served six are now considered single portions. At the very least, the government can stop subsidizing the junk food industry, as well as meat producers. According to jefftk.com, “The U.S government spends $38 billion each year to subsidize the meat and dairy industries, but only 0.04 percent of that (i.e., $17 million) each year to subsidize fruits and vegetables. A $5 Big Mac would cost $13 if the retail price included hidden expenses that meat producers offload onto society.”

    Reply

Trackbacks/Pingbacks

  1. Gray Area - […] What Are We Getting for All That Obamacare Spending? Copyright GrayArea 2023. All right reserved. […]

Submit a Comment

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *